trade – P2P Foundation https://blog.p2pfoundation.net Researching, documenting and promoting peer to peer practices Thu, 29 Dec 2016 23:22:00 +0000 en-US hourly 1 https://wordpress.org/?v=5.5.14 62076519 Project Of The Day: Fairpay https://blog.p2pfoundation.net/project-of-the-day-fairpay/2016/12/27 https://blog.p2pfoundation.net/project-of-the-day-fairpay/2016/12/27#comments Tue, 27 Dec 2016 15:38:06 +0000 https://blog.p2pfoundation.net/?p=62340 This year’s Brexit vote in Great Britain touted as effort to reclaim national sovereignty. In two years’ time, the British aim to reclaim freedom from the oppressive bureaucracy of the EU. Great Britain’s currency played a role in the decision. The Sterling’s status as a strong global currency allows the island nation to participate in... Continue reading

The post Project Of The Day: Fairpay appeared first on P2P Foundation.

]]>
This year’s Brexit vote in Great Britain touted as effort to reclaim national sovereignty. In two years’ time, the British aim to reclaim freedom from the oppressive bureaucracy of the EU. Great Britain’s currency played a role in the decision. The Sterling’s status as a strong global currency allows the island nation to participate in global trade.

Because of the recent U.S. election, progressives globally vow to work locally for change. Yet without an independent currency, they are all but forced to participate in the extractive economy that supports the new U.S. administration.

For billions of people, Bitcoin is not a viable option. However, Faircoop is launching Fairpay, aimed precisely at those who lack a smartphone. Those of us who do use iPhones can support the effort to build an independent, fair currency available to all.


 

Extracted from: https://fair.coop/order-the-fairpay-card-now-and-start-2017-by-committing-yourself-to-another-economy

Order the Fairpay card now and start 2017 by committing yourself to another economy for the whole year.

Extracted from: https://www.facebook.com/search/top/?q=P2P%20fairpay

Fairpay is:

– a NFC plastic card with payments charged with faircoin…

– A POS app for merchants

– A tool for payments without fees.

– A banking software for making charge the card or exchange faircoin and official currencies, so easy as using a bank account.

– A cashout system for merchants with SEPA transfer in 24 hours.

This technology will make faircoin the most advanced tool for easy physical payments in the cryptocurrency world. Making so easy the user experience as a is to use visa or mastercard. Still neither bitcoin have all of it together. Fairpay will be possible thanks to the collaboration between Faircoop and Chip chap.

Extracted from https://www.facebook.com/enricdurangiralt/posts/10211265838952073

In the last statement read: ” two milestones for the 2017. #Retornoenlibertad and build a new banking system for the people. So today same ad the next steps in each of those addresses. Let’s not leave for tomorrow what you can do today.

1. We just launch an online discussion group for the campaign #retornoenlibertad It’s a group of telegram (where we also have up to now the discussion of faircoop) Anyone who wants to collaborate is welcome, write to me privately and give me your user of telegram (possible create it in a minute in telegram. Org)

2. Ad that fairpay is going to be a reality already within a few weeks.

Fairpay will be a payment card for use in physical stores. An alternative to visa, Mastercard, no commissions. Using the latest technologies “Contactless” that the most innovative companies are implementing, because the cooperative is not at odds with innovation. A tool to extend the networks of social and solidarity economy to all, all over the world. The experience of use is going to be as easy as using a conventional system. Will be loaded with faircoin, but neither the user, or trade will notice is how easy it will be.

So you don’t have an excuse to take the plunge. Be easy even for trade change to euros if necessary. As easy as using a bank account and a lot cheaper than the corporations. You can also propose to the city of your people to use it, in order to strengthen the local economy, as some of you are interested. It is a key step to extend the new banking system of the people in the 2017. Keep your ears open for the launch, we’ll need you on board!

Extracted from: https://fair.coop/groups/faircoop-community/forum/topic/nfc-card-system-based-in-a-new-app-integrated-with-a-tpv-app-coming-very-soon/#post-12214

Keymaster

One important tool awaited for a long time by the Faircoop community is right now in strong process of development and will be ready in NFC card system which was discussed as a priority already one year ago in this thread: https://fair.coop/groups/faircoop-community/forum/topic/priorities-201515-development-of-local-payment-systems/

The system that is in the works is still better than we could envision, because it will be directly connected to a POS app, which will connect the shops accepting the card with a system of automatized exchange between faircoin and official currencies (euros or the currency available in each country). We will have access since the beginning to one day wire transfer in all the SEPA zone, connected to that system. And 2-4 days for external transfers. Other regions could add more fast options in the future.

The NFC app will be open source and owned by faircoop. The app development and the backend service, is provided by chip chap – in the future we could reproduce it, but this have a big cost- and the brand used for this service at short term will be fairtoearth which website will be updated in the same time.

This development has been advanced with money I got from selling faircoin to investors interested in this project. (In future could be recovered if appears other funders who supports it, without faircoin exchange)

The NFC card printing would be selfmanaged as part of this collaboration, making it very cheap, and in the next future would be important to invest in the machine who produce the nfc tags for the cards.

My proposal is, at same time, to make a deep update to use.fair-coin.org and use it, for promoting and facilitating the services related the NFC cards.

So, since this moment progressively the role of the local nodes, with their exchange offices capacities will evolve, and will not be so much to make directly the manual exchange, but to invite local shops to join and coordinate the relation with the local shops who can provide the service.

  • NFC (Near Field communication) is a technology similar than bluetooth, that makes possible to stablish connection between two devices when they are near. In this case the two devices are one smartphone and one card.

NFC tags:  Are just piece of information inserted in the card to be shared with the smartphone.

APP  (application). Is just any of the programs that you can install and run in your smartphone

POS (Point of Sale – TPV, terminal punto de venta in spanish).  Is the place where a retail transaction is completed. Actually is refered also as the point of service because it is not just a point of sale but also a point of return or customer order. Additionally, current POS terminal software may include additional features to cater for different functionality, such as inventory management, CRM, financials, warehousing, etc.

SEPA:  (Single Euro Payments Area). is a payment-integration initiative of the European Union for simplification of bank transfers denominated in euro.  SEPA consists of the 28 member states of the European Union, the four member states of the European Free Trade Association (Iceland, Liechtenstein, Norway and Switzerland), Monaco and San Marino.

  • Hey all,For this project, we will use the banking software of Chip chap for the faircoin cards and POS system. This payment system will be called fairpay.Any person with a card or merchant or a local node, who participate in fairpay project, will have one account in this banking software.Local nodes and registered merchants/shops will be able to create accounts for normal users.For a payment, the shop needs to have a smarphone or a card payments device, with NFC technology. Most of the recent devices have it.Card would have a cost of less than 0.1 eur. Could be given by free when someone wants to use it, if is charged after exchanging some amount of official currency.
  • Neither Faircoop, neither Chip chap, will receive any fee for creating a new account or for single payments, because the general vision is to provide an alternative without fees to visa and mastercard, etc… Anyway, the local nodes are free to decide any fee as local strategy for developing their work.
  • Shops could only accept cards or could also distribute cards and sell faircoins with their App. Some level of trust could be appreciated in order to let a shop distribute cards and sell faircoins.
  • Local nodes or the global faircoop where there is no local node, will be able to create accounts for merchants/shops

How faircoin cards will work

We could choose to include a QR from the faircoin address on the card, so then people with a card can charge the card or receive payments just with the QR.

POS System.

With the POS system, the merchants would be able to exchange the faircoins received to euros, from the panel on their account and receive a transfer to their banking account in 24 hours. This service would have a 1% fee by chip chap.

Faircoop should provide the liquidity in euros and faircoins, for covering the exchanges, if faircoop fails to do it, there is the option that chip chap get the liquidity from bittrex or that we stop the service until there is liquidity.

General panel use

The panel can be used as an online bank account + online wallet. We can decide each category of users which services can access.

For example people could:

– Charge the card online

– Empty the card online

– Send faircoins to an andress outside of the wallet.

– Change from euro to faircoin or faircoin to euro (this service would have 1% fee)

Organization elements.

A team for coordinating the project should be created. This team could be related to the european coop bank that also is being developed.

Faircoop could inform about this project in use.fair-coin.org. At same time fairtoearth.com could be used.

The local nodes should be able to ask for some amounts of cards for using at their local nodes. Then they could explain and provide the local merchants.

The shops which are not related to any local node could ask for it by their own; then the global faircoop team should use some criteria to confirm if they could be accepted for the way of participation they choose:

1- Accepting card payments

2 – Accepting card payments, distributing cards

  1. – Accepting card payments, distributing cards and selling faircoins.

(We could choose simplify and only organize to options, just accepting cards or distributing and selling together)

In the case of shops selling faircoins, they could receive euros that belongs to faircoop, then would be a task of local nodes to follow up that cash in order to recover it for managing for example. cashout needs. The panel will have info of the stats of the shops they manage for making easier following this data.

The post Project Of The Day: Fairpay appeared first on P2P Foundation.

]]>
https://blog.p2pfoundation.net/project-of-the-day-fairpay/2016/12/27/feed 1 62340
Project Of The Day: Community Exchange System https://blog.p2pfoundation.net/project-day-community-exchange-system/2016/06/01 https://blog.p2pfoundation.net/project-day-community-exchange-system/2016/06/01#respond Tue, 31 May 2016 22:19:05 +0000 https://blog.p2pfoundation.net/?p=56767 Have you ever had an “IDEA”? Perhaps it was a killer app, or 3D print design. Maybe you heard a complaint repeatedly and imagined a service to solve the problem. Or you had a vision of a song, a film, or a book. Your friends liked your idea. A few of them assured you your... Continue reading

The post Project Of The Day: Community Exchange System appeared first on P2P Foundation.

]]>
Have you ever had an “IDEA”?

Perhaps it was a killer app, or 3D print design. Maybe you heard a complaint repeatedly and imagined a service to solve the problem. Or you had a vision of a song, a film, or a book.

Your friends liked your idea. A few of them assured you your idea would make you rich. Others volunteered to help you make your idea a reality.

So, you investigated.  What would it take to convert your idea into a fortune? You could

  • set up an account on Fivrr,
  • create a shop on Apple or Google Play,
  • negotiate crypto-exchanges on Tor
  • pitch at SXSW

But these venues all have the same weakness.  And that weakness is money. You’re either trying to raise money, or exchange for money.

What if you could trade your idea for other forms of value?  What if could exchange your idea for:

  • products you use, or
  • services you need, or
  • access to groups you aspire to, or
  • expert advice, or
  • places to stay
  • social validation?

What if your idea, or talent, or service, or product could make you wealthy without “money”?

That is the value proposition of Community Exchange system.


Extracted from: https://www.community-exchange.org/home/

A World Free of Money

There are many ways of exchanging what we have and can do for the things we need. Money is just one of them. The internet revolution has brought us new ways without the unnecessary step of acquiring money first. Here we exchange and share what we have to offer for what others provide using a variety of exchange methods: record keeping, time exchange, direct exchange, barter, swapping, gifting and sharing. Simply by keeping track of who receives what from whom we can dispense with the ancient idea of exchange media and the apparatus required to manage them. This helps us focus on providing and requesting what is really needed instead of chasing after money.

Extracted from: https://www.community-exchange.org/home/how-it-works/

How It Works

The Community Exchange System (CES) is a web service that provides the tools for communities to set up and manage exchange and trade in their areas without using money. It also provides communities with a network that permits them to trade with other communities, wherever they are in the world.

The main object of the CES is to facilitate trade and exchange by providing a range of non-monetary exchange methods. This helps to build community by connecting people and providing a local support network.

By ‘trade’ we mean the normal activities of providing goods and services by ‘givers’, ‘producers’, ‘sellers’ or ‘providers’, and the receiving of these by ‘buyers’, ‘customers’, ‘clients’, ‘patients’, ‘consumers’, ‘receivers’, etc.

The CES serves two basic functions:

  • it is an online exchange system that facilitates exchange in a number of different ways
  • it is an online ‘marketplace’ where users advertise their skills, offerings and requirements

A new feature has been added to the CES softwaretime that allows you to record the time you have provided to other users. To get to it, log into your account and click on the [Trading] button at top, and then select Record Hours from the drop-down menu.

This new feature is really useful for barter/swap arrangements where the exchange is one hour of your time for one hour of someone else’s time. This feature allows you to keep a record of the hours you have provided. The recipient of your time can likewise record hours they have provided to you and the details will show in your combined records.

 

Photo by thetaxhaven

Photo by brizzle born and bred

The post Project Of The Day: Community Exchange System appeared first on P2P Foundation.

]]>
https://blog.p2pfoundation.net/project-day-community-exchange-system/2016/06/01/feed 0 56767
Markets Before and After Capitalism https://blog.p2pfoundation.net/markets-before-capitalism/2016/02/11 https://blog.p2pfoundation.net/markets-before-capitalism/2016/02/11#comments Thu, 11 Feb 2016 09:46:54 +0000 http://blog.p2pfoundation.net/?p=53891 Excerpted from a really interesting historical review by Jesse A. Myerson: (see below what she says about post-capitalist markets and de-marketing) “Markets predate capitalism by thousands of years. Almost from the very beginning of human history, there were markets. As early as the Ice Age, long before the rise of cities with permanently settled populations,... Continue reading

The post Markets Before and After Capitalism appeared first on P2P Foundation.

]]>
Excerpted from a really interesting historical review by Jesse A. Myerson:

(see below what she says about post-capitalist markets and de-marketing)

Markets predate capitalism by thousands of years.

Almost from the very beginning of human history, there were markets. As early as the Ice Age, long before the rise of cities with permanently settled populations, there were specialized meeting areas for ritual and trade between groups. When hunting and gathering bands began to settle on land to cultivate crops and domesticate animals, they created the conditions to produce something unprecedented: an economic surplus. By the Bronze Age, people had amassed sufficient “surplus food, oil, and wool,” as economic historian Michael Hudson writes, “to support a permanent superstructure of handicraft, mercantile and administrative occupations.” Temples became the first public institutions, functioning variously as storage facilities for the surplus resources of their communities, gathering places, trading depots, refuges from local feud justice, establishers of contract law, enforcers of trade obligations, and sponsors of standardized weights and measures.

Temples also employed the labor of dependents: war widows, orphans, the blind and infirm, and others who could not function in normal family contexts. Housing the workshops where these dependents wove, Mesopotamian temples consigned textiles to merchants under instructions to trade them abroad for raw materials not found between the Tigris and Euphrates: metal, stone, and hardwood. To facilitate this export enterprise and regulate the markets it sponsored, Sumer developed most of the major instruments of modern commerce during roughly the third millennium BCE — money, credit, interest, contracts, and legacies — and established profit-seeking mercantile operations as far away as Anatolia and the Indus Valley. Thus, roughly 4,000 years before the emergence of capitalism, we were economizing our resources by haggling in markets which connected people thousands of miles apart.

Deposit banking, insurance policies, corporations, municipal bond markets, and, what was crucial for all of these, double entry bookkeeping, were developed later on, but still well before capitalism, in medieval Venice between about the eleventh and fifteenth centuries CE. From there, merchants would acquire and peddle wares on an intercontinental scale: after Marco Polo extended the silk route to Venice, the lagoon nestled in the pit of the Adriatic Sea became the world’s chief hub of trade in commodities, bullion, and various financial instruments, with a market network connecting West Africa to Siberia, the South Pacific to England. As Wood points out, the feudal system was compatible not just with “advanced urban cultures, highly developed trading systems, and far-flung commercial networks” but indeed “profit-seeking middlemen, even highly developed merchant classes.” None of these, it follows, should be confused for, nor even considered evidence of, capitalism. Capitalism isn’t distinguished by its capacity to provide market opportunities, but by the imperatives the market places on its unique system of production.”

Capitalist Markets

“It wasn’t until hundreds of years after Marco Polo’s travels that the dramatic transformation of the system of production began—and in a curious place. Wood demonstrates that the capitalist “laws of motion” did not emerge in urban commercial centers, as is normally supposed, but in the countryside. Specifically, the English countryside. English landholding was inordinately concentrated, so “an unusually large proportion of land was worked not by peasant-proprietors but by tenants,” as Wood explains. For most of the feudal age, English tenancies were “Freehold leases,” with rents fixed by a legal or customary standard, but by the sixteenth century, a growing number were “Copyhold leases,” auctioned by landlords to the highest bidder, their rental value set at whatever the market would bear. The more competition there was in the market for rental land, the more notice landlords and their surveyors began to take of the “value above the oulde Rentes” that could be extracted through this market. And so England underwent great waves of land enclosure, separating the masses from direct access to the means of their own subsistence.

At this point, in addition to competing in a market for consumers, tenants were obliged to compete in a market for access to land. In the system emerging out of the particularly English invention of a land-rent market, farmers were subjected to a “systematic need to lower the costs of production in order to prevail in price competition.” Those who failed to compete in this market found themselves dispossessed of all but their own capacity to perform labor, which they flocked to cities to sell, or else to starve.

This, and not the availability of markets, is the essence of capitalism, the engine motoring in its depths. From this imposition, and thus this dispossession, capitalism sprang to life. Now the masses were at the mercy of a job market to obtain the means to reproduce themselves socially. Now the process of production was systematically subordinated to market imperatives: “competition, accumulation, and profit-maximization, and hence a constant systemic need to develop the productive forces.”

These imperatives, in turn, give capitalism its ability (and charge it with the necessity) to relentlessly expand in unprecedented ways and degrees. “It can and must,” as Wood insists, “constantly accumulate, constantly search out new markets, constantly impose its imperatives on new territories and new spheres of life, on all human beings and the natural environment.”

* Markets After Capitalism

“The key to imagining what post-capitalist markets might look like, according to David Schweickart, is to discard the unitary idea of “markets.” Too general a term to be useful, markets, Schweickart suggests, should be divided into three types: markets for goods and services, capital markets, and labor markets. The first sort was compatible with feudalism, and it can be compatible with socialism: with solid regulation, price discovery through market clearance is a useful tool in signaling demand and avoiding the shortages in goods and services that may result from clumsy, or capricious, central planning.

But the other markets are not nearly so capable in the resource-allotment division. Capital markets are prone to careening wildly between booms, when they allot far too many financial resources, and busts, when they allot far too few. Labor markets are volatile because of this careening, but even in the boom times, commonly maintain a reserve army of unemployed workers amid back-breaking overwork. It is these capital and labor markets, therefore, that Schweickart contends must be socialized to give rise to the next system. To these, I’d add two that might broadly be thought of as capital markets, but which beg different, if similar, solutions: the market for intellectual property and the market which birthed capitalism, land.

There are basically two strategies for de-marketing labor, and they work best together. The first is the aggressive encouragement of worker co-ops, including buying out (not bailing out) failing firms and leasing them to workers, giving workers the right to buy out their shops as an alternative to closure, and providing public financial and technological support for start-up co-ops. The more workers can become owners, the less they’ll have to work for wages, thus shrinking the labor market. The second strategy is to provide the option to exit the job market by filling out the welfare state: public health care, education, and “last resort” guaranteed employment, capped off with a basic income to subsidize culture- and community-production. The ability to survive without submitting to the dictates of the job market would incapacitate the capitalist imperative to compete with everybody else.

Co-ops also help to de-market capital, relocating ownership from stock market gamblers who are physically and sentimentally remote from the firm’s operations to workers who inherently give a damn about the fate of the firm and the labor they deploy for it. In addition to this, it is crucial to expand our public wealth funds in number and scope. The Alaska Permanent Fund, CalPERS, and even the Social Security trust funds are pools of capital whose income streams (dividends and interest) flow to the public. A national sovereign wealth fund and/or many regional ones would shrink capital markets. (It might make sense to emulate Alaska, using the fund to outlay the aforementioned basic income.) For best results, this should be held together by a public banking system, most easily run through the postal service, featuring a publicly-controlled mobile payments system.

De-marketing intellectual property is especially exhilarating, because we can skip the socialist step of moving ideas from private to public ownership, and go straight to the communist state of non-ownership. Ideas such as pharmacological discoveries, software developments, and works of media are immaterial, their digital representations as sound, video, image, text, etc. files infinitely reproducible at negligible cost. In order, therefore, to effect their decommodification, the government only needs to take a laissez faire approach to enforcing their patents, copyrights, etc. Beyond possibly brief, non-transferable licenses for authors and inventors (as the founders intended), there is no need for the government to impose artificial scarcity, without which, an infinitely abundant product will approach its “correct consumer price”: zero dollars.

Lastly, there are also already existent vehicles for democratic land management and development that can allow us to undo the initial act of capitalism and de-market land. Foremost, in recognition of the fact that the price of a location is determined by the desirability of the surrounding community, the government can impose a fee on land-owners equivalent to the ground rent they derive. Especially elegant would be to have these fees provide the initial investment into the public fund paying out the basic income, thus compensating everyone for their exclusion from the locations in question. Additionally, the government should devote public financing and its power of eminent domain to energetically foster Community Land Trusts. Perhaps most importantly, the government should massively grow the public housing stock so that it does not merely provide poor people undignified living conditions, but rather houses major swaths of large cities in modest, comfortable units. This last is probably the most difficult, seeing as how the federal government is prevented by law at the moment from financing public housing.

A socialism like this, with capital, labor, ideas and land brought out of the market and into the democratic sphere, could accommodate markets in goods and services without imposing on all of society the imperatives unique to capitalism. Mass liberation from capitalist market imperatives would effect reparations for the dispossession that incited the capitalist laws of motion. The system would no longer have the necessity, or perhaps even the means, to impose its relentless imperatives on you and me and the whole wide world.”

The post Markets Before and After Capitalism appeared first on P2P Foundation.

]]>
https://blog.p2pfoundation.net/markets-before-capitalism/2016/02/11/feed 1 53891